Comprehension

Smith did not invent economics. Joseph Schumpeter observed that “The Wealth of the Nations” did not contain “a single analytic idea, principle or method that was entirely new”. Smith’s achievement was to combine an encyclopaedic variety of insight, information and anecdote, and to distil from it a revolutionary doctrine. The resulting masterpiece is the most influential book about economics ever published. Remarkably, much of it speaks directly to questions that are still of pressing concern.
The pity is that Smith’s great book, like most classics (of 900 pages), is more quoted than read. All sides in today’s debates about economic policy have conspired to peddle a conveniently distorted version of its idea. If his spirit is still monitoring events, it will undoubtedly have celebrated the collapse of communism. But it must also long to meet the politicians who have taken charge of a fine reputation and not so fine profile. And put them right on one or two points. 
Today Smith is widely seen as intellectual champion of self-interest. This is a misconception. Smith saw no moral virtue in selfishness; on the contrary he saw its dangers. Still less was he a defender of capital over labour (he talked of the capitalist’s “mean rapacity”), of the rising bourgeoisie over the common folk. His suspicion of self-interest and his regard for the people as a whole come through clearly in one of his best-known remarks: “People of the same trade often meet together, even have merriment and diversion, but the conversation ends in a conspiracy against the public, or in some contrivance to raise prices.” Far from praising self-interest as a virtue, Smith merely observed it to be a driving economic force. In “The Wealth of Nations” he explained how this potentially destructive impulse is harnessed to the social good. What is to prevent greedy producers raising their prices until their customers can afford to pay no more? The answer is competition. If producers raise their prices too high, they create an opportunity for one or more among them to profit by charging less and thus selling more. In this way competition tames selfishness and regulates prices and quality. At the same time it regulates quantities. If buyers want more bread and less cheese, their demand enables bakers to charge more and obliges cheese-mongers to charge less. Profits in bread-making would rise and profits in cheese-making would fall; effort and capital would move from one task to the other.
Through Smith’s eyes, it is possible to marvel afresh at this fabulously powerful mechanism and to relish, as he did, the paradox of private gain yielding social good. Only more so, for the transactions that deliver a modern manufactured good to its customer are infinitely more complicated than those described by Smith. In his day, remember, the factory was still a novel idea: manufacturing meant pins and coats.
Amodern car is made of raw materials that have been gathered from all over the world, combined into thousands of intermediate products, sub-assembled by scores of separate enterprises. The consumer need know nothing of all this, any more than the worker who tapped the rubber for the tyres knows or cares what its final use will be. Every transaction is voluntary. Self-interest and competition silently process staggering quantities of information and direct the flow of good. Services, capital and labour– just as in Smith’s much simpler world. Far-sighted as he was, he would surely have been impressed. Mind you, modern man has also discovered something else. With great effort and ingenuity, and the systematic denial of personal liberty, governments can supplant self-interest and competition, and replace the invisible hand of market forces with collective endeavour and a visible input-output table. The result is a five-year waiting list for Trabants.
Because Smith was convinced that the market would, literally, deliver the goods, he wanted it, by and large, left alone. He said that governments should confine themselves to three main tasks: defending the people from the “violence and invasion of other independent societies”; protecting every member of society from the “injustice or oppression of every other member of it”; and providing “certain public works and certain public institutions, which it can never be for the interest of any individual, or small number of individuals, to erect and maintain.” Each of these jobs arises because the market in some ways fails. In the first two cases collective defence and the administration of justice– the failure is the so-called free-rider problem. People disguise what they are willing to pay for a service that must be provided to everybody or not at all; they want to consume it and let others meet the cost. However the third job– the provision of “certain public works and certain public institutions”– goes much wider. Indeed, to modern minds, it threatens to be all encompassing. It recognizes not only the free-rider problem but also other species of market failure notably, the effects of private transactions on third parties, or “externalities”. Smith has in mind roads, public education, and help for the destitute. As it turned out, millions of teachers, nurses, firemen, postmen, rubbish collectors, bus drivers and 57,000 varieties of civil servant have since marched through this opening.
Smith’s thinking already seems to permit a great deal of government intervention. Add some modern economics and the floodgates open. For instance, theorists have shown that if just one price in an economy is different from price under competition, efficiency may require other every price to be somewhat distorted as well. Less government intervention, it seems to follow, cannot be assumed to be better. Competition itself has changed out of recognition. Modern economies, it is said, are driven not by countless small producers, but by handful of giant enterprises and monopolistic trade unions. And the rapid pace of industrial change has made the externality of pollution far more obvious than before. Smith, admittedly, is a bit thin on global warming.
Above all, many have forgotten something that Smith saw clearly: that every advantage granted by government to one part of the economy puts the rest at a disadvantage.
Accordingly, he talked not of “intervention” at a too-neutral word-but of “preference” and “restraint”. Modern governments offer preference as though it costs nothing: the beneficiaries demand it as of right.
But Smith went further than revealing the penalty in every preference. He also understood that ministers, like markets, fail. A great virtue of unfettered competition, he said, was that “the sovereign is completely discharged from a duty, in the attempting to perform which he must always be exposed to innumerable delusions, and for the proper performance of which no human wisdom or knowledge could ever be sufficient.” Many of the reasons why markets fail are also reasons why governments fail at the same task. If the consumer refuses to reveal his preferences in a market setting, how are governments to discover them? All too often, moreover, government intervention is itself a cause of the market breaking down which becomes the reason for further rounds of intervention, and so on. In Britain think of tax preferences for housing, rent controls, planning, regulations; American think of tax preferences for borrowing, deposit insurance, leverage buy-outs, financial-market regulation. In one crucial respect, Smith’s arguments are even more powerful now than in his day. Naturally, he favoured free trade to prevent market failure: “By means of glasses, hothbeds, and hotwalls, very good grapes can be raised in Scotland, and very good wine too can be made of them at about thirty times the expense for which at least equally good can be brought from foreign countries. Would it be a reasonable law to prohibit the importation of all foreign wines, merely to encourage the making of claret and burgundy in Scotland?” Two centuries later, free trade is not just a matter of the cheapest supply; it is also the best way to force producers that might otherwise be near-monopolies to compete. It is perfect folly to complain that today’s big companies render the invisible hand powerless, and to conclude that barriers to trade must go up: trade and competition need each other more than ever before.
Smith was a pragmatist. The principles he expounded on the proper role of government are flexible if anything, too flexible. They are a remainder that imperfect markets are usually cleverer than imperfect governments, but they cannot draw a line to separate good intervention from bad. If governments and voters could be guided by two Smithian precepts, however, the market system that has worked so well would work even better.
First, the competitive clash of self interest against self-interest, however imperfect, has built-in safeguards. Before governments exert their monopoly power to displace it, they must justify themselves. Let the burden of proof always be on them. Second, when preference or restraint are judged to be necessary, use market forces to apply them. Tariffs are better than quotas; taxes are better than bans or direct controls; allocating resources by price (e.g. in health or education) is better than allocating them by fiat, even if the services are then provided “free” (but never forget those inverted commas) to their consumers.

Question: 1

Smith's attitude to the virtues of self-interest can be best described as

Show Hint

When the author recognizes a force as inevitable but proposes realistic controls instead of moral judgment, the stance is generally pragmatic.
Updated On: Aug 7, 2025
  • pragmatic
  • cynical
  • skeptical
  • supportive
Hide Solution
collegedunia
Verified By Collegedunia

The Correct Option is A

Solution and Explanation

From the passage, Smith does not see moral virtue in selfishness and is aware of its dangers. However, he acknowledges self-interest as a real and powerful economic force that can be harnessed for the social good through competition. This view reflects a practical, realistic approach rather than moral approval or disapproval — hence, pragmatic.
- He is \textit{not cynical} because he does not view self-interest purely as corrupt or negative.
- He is \textit{not skeptical} because he recognizes the economic utility of self-interest.
- He is \textit{not supportive} in a moral sense because he warns about its dangers.
Thus, his approach balances acknowledgment of its role with a call for competitive regulation, which is pragmatic.
Was this answer helpful?
0
0
Question: 2

According to Adam Smith

Show Hint

When answering RC questions, look for the option that captures the exact role or function described by the author, not just a related fact.
Updated On: Aug 7, 2025
  • selfishness is dangerous.
  • competition is the result of ’mean rapacity’
  • self interest always leads to competition.
  • competition regulates quantities.
Hide Solution
collegedunia
Verified By Collegedunia

The Correct Option is D

Solution and Explanation

From the passage, Smith explains that competition plays a regulatory role in the economy.
It prevents producers from excessively raising prices and helps in adjusting quantities and quality according to demand.
He specifically notes that competition also regulates quantities, as shifts in consumer demand reallocate resources between industries.
This makes option (d) correct.
- Option (a) is true in the passage but not the specific answer to 'according to Adam Smith' in this context.
- Option (b) is not his description of competition, rather of capitalist greed.
- Option (c) is partially true but incomplete; competition is more than a result of self-interest.
Was this answer helpful?
0
0
Question: 3

All of the following are reasons for market failure except:

Show Hint

For “except” questions, identify all options that fit the category in the passage, then eliminate them to find the outlier.
Updated On: Aug 7, 2025
  • The effects of private transactions on third parties.
  • People would like to consume goods without paying for them.
  • Unfettered and unbridled trade.
  • Government intervention.
Hide Solution
collegedunia
Verified By Collegedunia

The Correct Option is C

Solution and Explanation

In the passage, market failure is linked to the free-rider problem, externalities, and the inability of markets to provide certain public goods.
However, 'unfettered and unbridled trade' is not presented as a cause of market failure—it is actually the competitive mechanism that can correct inefficiencies.
Thus, option (c) is correct as the exception.
Was this answer helpful?
0
0
Question: 4

Adam Smith is most likely to agree with the statement:

Show Hint

When matching a statement to the author, look for direct quotations or paraphrases from the passage.
Updated On: Aug 7, 2025
  • It is necessary for capital to exploit labour if competition and low prices are to be engendered.
  • Businessmen would form cartels given the chance.
  • Lesser government intervention is better.
  • Collective endeavour could be the basis of economic growth.
Hide Solution
collegedunia
Verified By Collegedunia

The Correct Option is B

Solution and Explanation

Smith famously remarked that people of the same trade often conspire to raise prices, implying that businessmen will form cartels if possible.
Option (b) directly reflects this view.
- Option (a) misrepresents his stance.
- Option (c) is sometimes true but not the main agreement point here.
- Option (d) is contrary to his preference for market mechanisms.
Was this answer helpful?
0
0
Question: 5

Which of the following situations is not an instance of market failure?

Show Hint

Differentiate between failures of economic systems and failures in legal or political systems when answering market-related questions.
Updated On: Aug 7, 2025
  • A government practising apartheid.
  • A specialist doctor charging high fees.
  • Poor development of roads and railways.
  • A murderer going scot-free.
Hide Solution
collegedunia
Verified By Collegedunia

The Correct Option is D

Solution and Explanation

Market failure occurs when resources are allocated inefficiently, often due to externalities, public goods, or imperfect competition.
A murderer going scot-free is a failure of the justice system, not the market system.
Thus, (d) is correct as it does not fit the economic definition of market failure.
Was this answer helpful?
0
0
Question: 6

The 'free rider' problem results in the need for all of the following except

Show Hint

Free rider problems are usually tied to public goods — think defence, infrastructure, and services available to all.
Updated On: Aug 7, 2025
  • government laws to prevent crime.
  • a national defence budget.
  • a national R & D centre for an industry.
  • a United Nations peace keeping force.
Hide Solution
collegedunia
Verified By Collegedunia

The Correct Option is A

Solution and Explanation

The free rider problem involves individuals benefiting from goods or services without paying for them, especially in public goods like defence, research, or international peacekeeping.
Government laws to prevent crime do not directly address the free rider issue.
Hence, option (a) is correct as the exception.
Was this answer helpful?
0
0
Question: 7

Based on the passage, competitions will directly affect all of the following except:

Show Hint

Identify what the passage explicitly attributes to competition, and separate it from outcomes driven by other market forces.
Updated On: Aug 7, 2025
  • quantity of a good produced.
  • quality of a good produced.
  • direction of flow of goods.
  • price of goods sold.
Hide Solution
collegedunia
Verified By Collegedunia

The Correct Option is C

Solution and Explanation

The passage states that competition regulates prices, quality, and quantities.
The 'direction of flow of goods' is influenced more by demand and supply patterns rather than competition alone.
Thus, (c) is correct as the factor not directly affected by competition.
Was this answer helpful?
0
0
Question: 8

We can conclude from the passage that:

Show Hint

Look for cause-effect patterns in the passage to infer conclusions, especially when the author describes cycles or repeating outcomes.
Updated On: Aug 7, 2025
  • government control is often self propagating.
  • rulers are prone to delusions.
  • governments often fail because markets also fail.
  • government actions rarely have justifications.
Hide Solution
collegedunia
Verified By Collegedunia

The Correct Option is A

Solution and Explanation

Smith argues that government intervention can lead to further intervention, creating a self-perpetuating cycle.
This matches option (a) as the correct inference from the passage.
Was this answer helpful?
0
0
Question: 9

Based on the passage, we could say that Adam Smith would not support

Show Hint

When an author consistently promotes free trade, they are usually against any restrictive trade tools like licences or quotas.
Updated On: Aug 7, 2025
  • government intervention.
  • corporation
  • taxes.
  • import licences.
Hide Solution
collegedunia
Verified By Collegedunia

The Correct Option is D

Solution and Explanation

Smith favoured free trade and opposed restrictions such as import licences, which hinder competition.
Thus, he would not support (d) 'import licences'.
Was this answer helpful?
0
0
Question: 10

All the following characteristics of the modern world are used as arguments for government intervention except:

Show Hint

Pay attention to whether a detail is simply descriptive or actually used as a reason or argument in the passage.
Updated On: Aug 7, 2025
  • advanced and costly research in basic science.
  • the far greater complexity of the modern manufacturing process.
  • increased pollution and environmental hazards.
  • the pre-eminence of large corporations.
Hide Solution
collegedunia
Verified By Collegedunia

The Correct Option is B

Solution and Explanation

The complexity of manufacturing is described in the passage but not as a reason for government intervention.
Reasons given include public goods, externalities, and large corporations' power.
Hence, (b) is correct as the exception.
Was this answer helpful?
0
0
Question: 11

Based on the passage, the following can be inferred, except which of the following?

Show Hint

For “except” inference questions, eliminate all options that are clearly supported, then carefully examine the remaining choice for subtle contradictions.
Updated On: Aug 7, 2025
  • Governments must act only when necessary.
  • High customs duties are an acceptable way to restrict a change.
  • High taxation is better than bans.
  • The role of governments must be more flexible.
Hide Solution
collegedunia
Verified By Collegedunia

The Correct Option is B

Solution and Explanation

Smith preferred tariffs to quotas, but the passage does not endorse 'high customs duties'—only that tariffs are better than outright bans.
Thus, (b) is the inference not supported by the passage.
Was this answer helpful?
0
0
Question: 12

The most serious problem of modern government is that they

Show Hint

Look for key criticisms in the author’s tone — they often point directly to the correct answer in such evaluative questions.
Updated On: Aug 7, 2025
  • hire too many people.
  • offer advantages to groups as if it costs nothing.
  • are often unwise in their decisions.
  • tax the citizens too much.
Hide Solution
collegedunia
Verified By Collegedunia

The Correct Option is B

Solution and Explanation

The passage criticizes modern governments for offering preferences without recognizing the costs to others in the economy.
Thus, (b) is correct.
Was this answer helpful?
0
0

Top Questions on Reading Comprehension

View More Questions